New research reports low land-use
efficiency in communally owned land in eastern Indonesia. But as Stein
Kristiansen and Linda Sulistiawati find, it is underuse rather than
overexploitation of common–pool resources on agricultural, pastoral and forest
land that is the problem.
Communal ownership of agricultural,
pastoral, and forest land is typical in poor and peripheral parts of Indonesia,
as elsewhere in Asia.
Only five per cent of Indonesia’s
land area is formally registered for private ownership or user rights, and only
a fraction of that is freehold property. With population growth, local
expectations of welfare improvement, and external commercial interests,
pressure on land and livelihoods is increasing—as is the number of land
conflicts.
In research spanning 18 peripheral
sites in East Nusa Tenggara and Maluku, two of Indonesia’s poorest provinces,
we investigated the roles of three types of institutions—liberalised land
markets, the state government, and local adat (customs or traditions)—in
balancing the goals of increased land efficiency, livelihood security, and
conflict avoidance.
We found that land efficiency,
measured as the annual total production value per area of land, is typically
much lower for communally owned land than for commercial plantations or
pasture. As the potential value of land goes up, the number of land conflicts
is increasing—both within families and among villages.
Livelihood security, however, is
seen as strong and stable, and the vast majority of villagers reported seeing
no environmental degradation and said they have access to enough land and tools
to make a ‘decent living’. Agricultural land typically belongs to clans or
villages; individuals or families have stable user rights but generally no
chance of obtaining official freehold titles. The distribution of user rights
and control of land use is governed by traditional institutions (adat).
The vast majority of our 640 survey
respondents did not regard privatisation (the freedom to buy and sell land) as
the right path to greater land-use efficiency. Yet most people said that their
village could produce more economic value from agriculture, grazing land, or
forests if the land were distributed or used in another way. Respondents in
most places reported extensive areas of ‘sleeping’ land that could potentially
be used productively.
If user and harvest rights were
distributed permanently and more equitably among families, many areas of common
agricultural, grazing, or forest land could be used more efficiently. The
skepticism about free markets for land-ownership transactions is based on the
fear of escalating land conflicts and the marginalisation of poor people in places
where working the land is the only way to make a living.
Instead of the ability to buy and
sell land, people generally want permanent user rights. For 95 per cent of
respondents, the main reason for certifying land would be to avoid land
conflicts in the future. Having the option to sell the land after certification
was important for less than four per cent of respondents.
State government institutions are
also mostly distrusted as instruments for higher land-use efficiency and
sustainable livelihoods. We heard many examples of corrupt practices and
government–business relations that have undermined ecological sustainability
and benefited only a small elite—particularly in the use of forest areas, where
the state government claims ownership, but also in the distribution of farm
land in state-sponsored irrigation schemes. Customary law is a more respected
instrument for organising land user rights and solving land disputes than
national laws and formal judicial institutions.
Most people in our study areas pay
much respect to adat institutions, as represented by customary law, clan
elders, and traditional communal assemblies. As many as 90 per cent of
respondents said that productive land in their village is distributed according
to ‘fair principles’, of which communal consensus and ancestral obligations
were considered the most important.
At the same time, most respondents
said that land in their village could be distributed more equitably or given on
more reasonable conditions. The main argument held for having an improved
system of land distribution is the need to spread land user rights more evenly
among village families.
Many also say that land user rights
should be distributed more fairly among genders. Young people—especially
women—see a need to amend local traditional institutions to meet new demands
for participation and democracy and revised principles of justice. Adat
reflects old standards of social stratification, gender inequality, and local
economic exploitation, and the local elite’s capturing of such institutions may
prohibit economic progress.
The Indonesian government should
acknowledge and register communal land ownership with specified and registered
family user rights and inalienability. Such registering could also be used to
make productive communal land taxable, which would increase local government
income and could enhance land-use productivity.
Stein Kristiansen is based at the Universitetet I Agder, Norway
and Linda Sulistiawati at Gadjah Mada University, Indonesia.
This article is based on the the
authors’ recent publication in the Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies:
‘Traditions, Land Rights, and Local Welfare Creation: Studies from Eastern
Indonesia’.
No comments:
Post a Comment