The EU Is Rotting (And Its Banks Are
Insolvent)
The EU
as a political construction is in a state of terminal decay. We know this for
one reason and one reason alone: its core principal is the state is superior to
its people. A system of government can only work over the longer term if it
recognises that it is the servant of the people, not its master. It matters not
what electoral system is in place, so long as this principal is adhered to.
The EU executive in Brussels does not accept electoral primacy. It
shares with Marxist communism a belief in statist primacy instead. The only
difference between the two creeds is Marx planned to rule the world, while
Brussels is on the way to ruling Europe.
The methods of satisfying their objectives differ. Marx advocated civil
war on a global scale to destroy capitalism and the bourgeoisie, while Brussels
has progressively taken on powers that marginalise national parliaments. Both
creeds share a belief in an all-powerful executive. The comparison with Marxism
does not flatter the EU, and suggests it has a limited life and that we may be
on the verge of seeing the EU beginning to disintegrate. Despite economic
evolution in the rest of the world, like Marxian communists Brussels is stuck
with a failing economic and political creed.
It has no mechanism for compromise or adaptation. A rebellion from
Greece was put down, the British voted for Brexit, which is proving impossible
to negotiate, and now Italy thinks it can partially escape from this statist
version of Hotel California. The Italians are making huge mistakes. The rebel
parties forming a coalition government want to stay in the EU but are looking
to exit from the euro. Putting aside the impossibility of change for a moment,
they have it the wrong way around. If they are to achieve anything, they should
be exiting the EU and staying in the euro. Let me explain, starting with the
politics, before considering the economics.
As stated above, the EU is quasi-Marxist, placing the state above the
people. The Italian government has collaborated with Brussels to enslave its
own people as vassals of the EU super-state. If there is a revolt in Italy,
this is what the electorate is rebelling against. Faceless eurocrats tell the
Italian people what to do and what to think. The people are discontent with
both the super-state and their own weak governments.
The two parties forming the latest coalition are too frightened to blame
the EU, and instead propose to beg for debt forgiveness and say they are
considering leaving the euro. But without a clear vision, and understanding why
the Italian electorate is discontent, this coalition will turn out, in one of
Boris Johnson’s memorable phrases, to be comprised of little more than supine
protoplasmic invertebrate jellies. Greece is the precedent. This makes it easy
for the EU to deal with the Italians. They will get nothing.
The economic argument, that Italy would be better with her own currency,
is insane. With a history of weak irresponsible governments, it is far better
for the currency to be beyond Italy’s control. However, Keynesian commentators
are sympathetic to the weak currency argument, believing that the euro was
constructed for the benefit of Germany. Italy, along with the other
Mediterranean members, is said to be paying the price. This, they allege, is
the fatal flaw in the one-size-fits-all euro. This interpretation of the
monetary situation is baloney. It ignores the fact that Italy’s debt rocketed
after the formation of the euro, because the cost of borrowing for Italy fell
towards Germany’s borrowing rates, thanks to the guarantee of eventual
unification. The difference was Germany borrowed to invest in production, while
the Italian government borrowed to spend. The problem today is the profligacy
of the past has caught up with Italy, and its government must stop borrowing.
Setting up a lira alternative, or the mooted mini-BOTs, is an ill
thought out concept that only makes matters worse. The mini-BOT proposal
appears to be for an issue of certificates backed by future tax revenues to be
used to pay the government’s creditors. They would then circulate like bills
drawn on the state, but at a discount to reflect both their time value and the
fact they are not euros. It seems to not occur to the promoters of schemes like
this that the state’s creditors will insist on payment in euros.
Promoters of schemes like mini-BOTs are monetary cranks, incentivised by
a desire to avoid reality. The Italian government has been using this sort of
hocus-pocus for years, mostly with securitisation of future income streams,
such as the national lottery. Mini-BOTs appear to be a proposal for just one
more throw of the dice.
It’s hardly surprising that the Italian people are fed up with their
establishment and feel they can only collectively undermine it by voting
against it at election time. But it is too late, because the state, and
therefore the banks, are already irretrievably bust, a fact barely concealed by
the ECB’s funding of the Italian government at near-zero interest rates through
the purchase of government bonds. Not only is the ECB in denial over Italy’s
financial situation, but also Italy is firmly imprisoned.
EU Banks are Insolvent as Well
The disruption of an Italian withdrawal from the euro would be fatal for
the EU’s banking system on at least four levels.
- The
support from the ECB for the Italian banks would be withdrawn, which would
have the potential to allow a cascade of bank failures in Italy to
develop, either as a result of bad debts crystallising within the system,
or due to balance sheet deterioration from falling Italian government bond
prices.
- Problems
for banks will arise when past loans remain denominated in euros, while
their balance sheets are transitioned into a new, weakening currency. The
Italian banks lack the margins to weather lop-sided balance sheets, whose
assets are denominated in a declining currency relative to the currency of
their liabilities.
- There
will be a rush for residents in other Eurozone countries to reduce and
eliminate their Italian commitments, amounting to a banking run against
the whole country. The only political solution would be to impose
draconian capital controls between Italy and the rest of the world,
including other EU member states.
- Lastly,
there is the threat to the ECB and the euro-system itself.
These require little elaboration, expect perhaps for the threat to the
ECB and the euro-system. The ECB has been buying large quantities of Italian
bonds, effectively financing the Italian government’s excess spending, at
yields that are ridiculously low. In effect, the ECB has put itself in an
impossible position, and as the Italian situation worsens, the debate over the
fate of TARGET2
imbalances is bound to intensify.1 These are shown in the chart below, which is
of balances at end-March.
So long as the euro-system holds together, we are reassured that these
imbalances do not matter. However, with the Italian central bank in debt to the
system to the tune of a net €447bn, how these imbalances would be dealt with on
an Italian exit from the euro without a collapse of the system is an
interesting question. And it is worth noting that Spain’s central bank is also
in the hole for €390bn, just in case the Spanish electorate, or even the
Catalans or Basques get ideas of leaving as well.
The Bundesbank is owed a net €896bn and will be extremely nervous about
Italy. The ECB itself also owes a net €235bn to all the national central banks.
When the ECB buys Italian government debt, the Banca d’Italia acts on its
behalf. The Italian bonds are held at the Banca d’Italia, and the money is owed
to it. To the extent the ECB has bought Italian bonds, the overall negative
balance at the Banca d’Italia is reduced, so its deficits with the other
national banks in the system are actually greater than the €447bn shown, by the
amount owed to it by the ECB.
In short, it is hard to see how Italy can leave the euro without the ECB
having to formally guarantee all TARGET2 deficits. It is not impossible and the
guarantee is already implied, but the ECB won’t want anyone questioning its own
solvency, so we can safely assume an exit will not be permitted, for one simple
reason: the system and the banks in it are only solvent so long as the system
is unchallenged.
The question over Italy’s euro membership may not arise anyway, because
the new coalition does not yet know what it wants. The Italians must also be
dissuaded from their desire for debt forgiveness, for the same reasons the
Greeks were similarly deterred. And as the Greeks found, trying to negotiate
with the EU and the ECB was like talking to a brick wall. The Italians will
experience the same difficulties. We can dismiss any idea that because Italy is
a far bigger problem, they have negotiating clout. A brick wall remains a brick
wall.
So far as Brussels and Frankfurt (the home of the ECB) are concerned,
they are always in the right. The European project and the euro are more
important than the individual member nations, and their electorates have no say
in the matter. We often take this to be arrogance, which is a mistake. It is
worse: like Marxists, the eurocrats have unarguable conviction on their side.
Across the table will sit the Italians, with no political beliefs worth
mentioning, and all too readily frightened by the consequences of their own
actions.
This is the way the EU works. Inevitably, in a faceless statist system
such as this there are always problems at the national level to deal with. Then
there are localised difficulties, such as Deutsche Bank, whose share price
tells us it is failing. But in that event, it will doubtless be rescued because
of its enormous derivative exposure, the containment of eurozone systemic risk,
and German pride. The ECB has shown great skill at bluffing its way through
these ands other problems and is likely to continue to succeed in doing so,
except for one particular circumstance, which is the crisis stage of the credit
cycle.
The Credit Cycle Will Be the EU’s Undoing
It is a common misconception that the world has a business cycle: that
merely puts the blame on the private sector for periodic booms and busts. The
truth is every boom and bust has its origins in central bank monetary policy
and fractional reserve banking.
A central bank first attempts to stimulate the economy with low interest
rates, having injected base money into the economy to rescue the banks from the
previous crisis. The central bank continues to suppress interest rates,
inflating assets and facilitating the financing of government deficits.
This is followed by the expansion of bank credit as banks recognise that
trading conditions in the non-financial economy have improved. Price inflation
unexpectedly but inevitably increases, and interest rates have to rise. They
rise to the point where earlier malinvestments begin to be liquidated and a
loan repayment crisis develops in financial markets.
It is fundamentally a credit cycle, not a business one. Central bankers
do not, with very few exceptions, understand they are the cause. And the few
central bankers who do understand are unable to influence monetary policy by
enough to change it. By not understanding that they create the crisis
themselves, central bankers believe they can control all financial risks
through regulation and intervention, which is why they are always taken by
surprise when a credit crisis hits them.
For these reasons we know it is only a matter of time before the world
faces another credit crisis. The next one is likely to be unprecedented in its
violence, even exceeding that of the last one in 2008/09, because of the scale
of additional monetary reflation that has taken place over the last ten years.
The further accumulation of debt in the intervening period also means that a
smaller increase in price inflation, and therefore a lower height for interest
rates will trigger it.
My current expectation is that a global debt liquidation and credit
crisis is not far away and will occur by the end of Q1 in 2019, perhaps even by
the end of this year. The problem is a global one and we know not where it will
break. But once it does, the ECB and the euro will possibly face the most
violent deflation in modern history, even exceeding the global slump of the
1930s. We know in advance what the supposed solution will be: monetary
hyperinflation to bail out the banks, governments and the indebted.
The effects on prices in the Eurozone are unlikely to be as delayed as
they have been in the current cycle, partly because of the sheer scale of the
issuance of new money and credit required to stabilise the financial system,
partly because the euro is subordinate to the dollar as a safe-haven currency,
and partly because of its limited history as a medium of exchange.
Brexit
If I am only half right over the timing of the next credit crisis, it
will be at the same approximate time as Britain is due to exit the EU in March
2019. Logically, Brexit should not be deflected by the credit crisis and the
Eurozone catastrophe, but the statist instincts of the British government could
be to put the whole Brexit process on hold in the interests of global
government unity, at least while the management of the larger credit crisis is
addressed. The coordination of policy at the G20 level seems bound to take
precedence over potentially disruptive political issues such as Brexit.
So, despite the referendum commitment, even Britain may continue to be
trapped in the rotting EU super-state for a while longer, defying the wishes of
the electorate. As foreshadowed in Hayek’s The Road to Serfdom, the EU and the
British government will take the opportunity from crisis to increase their
control over their individual peoples, eroding further the limited freedoms
left to them.
Meanwhile, the British find themselves in a similar position to the
Italians. The EU simply refuses to accept the British electoral mandate,
because so far as it is concerned, it is not a matter for British voters.
Brussels is reassured that there are powerful forces in the British
establishment that will undermine Britain’s negotiating position. They are
confident that Britain will never leave the EU, because it won’t be allowed.
Consequently the British Brexit team finds it is trying to negotiate with that
uncompromising brick wall.
The Marxist-like certainty in the EU’s position compares with the
British lack of commitment to any sound position. The Conservative government
only pays lip service to free markets, unwilling to argue the case for them.
Nor can it stand up for the principal of democratic supremacy of the British
electorate, which, despite the mantra of acting on the instructions from the
referendum, it appears willing to compromise. It turns out that despite the
efforts of Brexiteers such as Boris Johnson, the British government, like the
Italians government, turns out to be a supine protoplasmic invertebrate jelly,
which places its short-term survival instincts above its electoral
responsibilities.
At this point, we can only surmise that, like the old Soviet Union, the
EU’s political grip remains as firm as ever. The problem is that the denial of
free markets and the supremacy of the super-state are gently rotting the EU
from within. The Euro-sceptic instinct to abandon it for a more progressive
world outside the EU is surely right. But the EU’s precariousness will only be
fully exposed by the next credit crisis and the ECB’s monetary response to it, which
will end up collapsing the euro.
About the author:
*Alasdair Macleod is the Head of Research at GoldMoney.
*Alasdair Macleod is the Head of Research at GoldMoney.
No comments:
Post a Comment