Democracy
and political opposition are supposed to go hand in hand. But opposition did
not emerge as automatically as expected after Indonesia democratised in 1998.
Instead, Indonesian presidents shared power widely among political parties. The
result has been an Indonesian style of party
cartelisation that differs significantly from canonical cases of
party cartelisation in Europe. Yet it exhibits the same troubling outcome for
democratic accountability: the stunted development of a clearly identifiable
opposition.
Party cartelisation
occurs when political parties are willing to share executive power with all
other parties regardless of political affiliation. All significant political
parties are brought into a ‘party cartel’ — a ruling coalition of political
parties that share power despite some having campaigned directly against each
other.
Presidential
power sharing is a strategic political game. Of particular importance are the
rules governing selection of the chief executive — in Indonesia’s case, always
a president. If a president is elected by the Parliament, as in Indonesia from
1999–2004, then the president is an agent of the Parliament. The president can
be expected to share power, roughly proportionally, with the parties in the
Parliament that selected the president.
Since the
advent of direct presidential elections in 2004, Indonesian democratic
competition has unsurprisingly assumed more of a government-versus-opposition
cast. A president elected by the people should theoretically be an agent of the
people and therefore face less imperative to share power with those who not
only played no role in electing the president but in many cases directly
opposed the new president’s candidacy.
There is an
implicit assumption that a president will share power with whichever parties
helped put the president in power. This can be described as a
power-sharing arrangement where presidents only share power with parties that
were supportive during the election campaign. Call this arrangement ‘victory’.
In this situation, the opposition is easily identifiable as whoever lost the
election.
But what if
‘victory’ is not the power-sharing game presidents play? A president might
offer to share power with any and all parties that promise to support the new
presidency, even if those parties earlier opposed the presidential candidate.
Call this other power-sharing arrangement ‘reciprocity’. If a president prefers
or is pressured into a ‘reciprocity’ arrangement, identifiable party opposition
may vanish — as it did in Indonesia from 1999–2004 — even in a perfectly
functional and democratic electoral system.
Party
cartelisation in Indonesia rests upon presidential willingness to share
executive power with any and all other political parties (‘reciprocity’).
Direct presidential elections will only disrupt or dismantle the cartelised
party system if presidents build coalitions comprised of supportive parties
from the election campaign as well as non-party allies whose election promises
roughly align with the president’s (‘victory’).
There are
two critical wrinkles in this analysis to consider, however.
The first is
that presidents not only make strategic choices about whom to share power with
but also about how much power each partner will receive. Presidents can reward
existing supporters by handing them a disproportionately large share of cabinet
seats while punishing previous opponents by giving them a disproportionately
small share.
This means
that it matters not only whether presidents share power with parties that
opposed them during the election (‘reciprocity’) but also whether presidents
hand out a disproportionate number of cabinet seats to certain coalition
partners. The more willing Indonesian presidents are to sideline their former
opponents, the more they shift from a ‘reciprocity’- to a ‘victory’-style
power-sharing arrangement and the better the prospects become for identifiable
opposition to emerge and strengthen in Indonesia.
The second
caveat is that presidential coalitions do not necessarily reflect the
president’s strategic preferences. Although presidents can choose to enter a
‘victory’ arrangement by decree, a ‘reciprocity’ arrangement requires both the
president and a given political party to come to an agreement before the latter
is brought into the party cartel. Whether a president seeking to share
executive influence with political parties regardless of political affiliation
can actually find willing coalition partners thus depends on hard political
bargaining. Even when a coalitional outcome seems to reflect a desire to drop an
unsupportive political party, the president may have just failed to ‘seal the
deal’ with active negotiating partners in an ongoing attempt to enter a
‘reciprocity’ arrangement.
Has the
shift to direct presidential elections emboldened Indonesia’s presidents since
2004 to pursue ‘victory’ coalitions? Or are the directly elected presidents
still trying to form broad and politically disparate political coalitions
(‘reciprocity’) and simply failing to strike bargains?
Both former
president Susilo Bambang Yudhoyono and current President Joko ‘Jokowi’ Widodo
made vigorous efforts to forge alliances
across the full range of Indonesian parties. The spectre of full party
cartelisation of Indonesia’s 1999–2004 period lingers, more than a decade after
direct presidential elections were introduced and the party cartel was first
disrupted.
Indonesia’s
experience with democratic power sharing suggests that presidents may sometimes
see broad coalitions as a source instead of a drain on
their power and resources. Oversized coalitions are typically thought of as
being more expensive to maintain. But this may not be how presidents see things
at all, at least under certain conditions. Oversized coalitions may be a way
for presidents to spread the same amount of resources across more claimants,
thus ensuring that no single partner can become too strong as a rival.
Party
cartelisation has abated in Indonesia, but not vanished. And it could still
easily come back in its most extreme form. Even if it does not, the public
willingness of all parties to consider such power-sharing alliances means that
Indonesia’s voters can never be confident that a vote for one party is a vote
against any other.
Dan Slater
is Professor of Political Science at the University of Michigan.
No comments:
Post a Comment