Friday, May 4, 2012

Dysfunctional Rule in China, India and the US Triggers Populism and Inequality


As news of political intrigue, corruption and human rights abuse tumble out of a hitherto tightly-managed Chinese system and as a slowdown in its frenzied growth rates seems likely in the near future, the triumphalist story of a “Beijing consensus” on authoritarian state-controlled capitalism looks a bit shabby now. But the other model practiced in capitalist democracies, like the United States and India, is looking wobbly, as well.

Dysfunctional government and rising inequality have triggered a populism that bodes ill for both systems. The standard measures of income inequality, like the Gini coefficient, is extremely high and increasing for China and the United States. While India does not regularly collect income-distribution data, occasional estimates suggest an even higher value than in China. In social indicators for the poor, like basic health and education, India and the United States are below what is average for their levels of income. The high fees charged in schools and hospitals in China have shut out many of the poor.


Competitive populism


In China, populism takes the form of wallowing in nationalist glory and a form of nationalist petulance; the government tries to manipulate this in deflecting domestic criticism by pointing to an interventionist West and building wasteful “image projects.” In India and the United States populism takes the form of short-term pandering by politicians.


Chinese authoritarianism has made it easy for the elite to convert political power into massive wealth and rampant crony capitalism — the 2011 Hurun Report estimates that the 70 richest members of the National People’s Congress have a combined net worth of $90 billion. There is evidence to believe that the too-big-to-fail state-owned companies and politically-connected private firms may have led to a serious misallocation of capital, blocked the entry of new firms and the exit of inefficient ones, spelling trouble for China’s prospects of going beyond the simple catch-up to the technology frontier.


An atmosphere of tight control over a free flow of ideas and creativity will also curtail innovation. Without innovation, China cannot sustain its high rate of growth, as the artificially low prices of land and capital for politically-favored firms become difficult to maintain and the supply of cheap labor exhausts.


This is of little comfort for the world’s democracies. India and the United States, for example, are suffering from policy paralysis delivered by a dysfunctional democracy.


In India, public resentment builds over corruption in high places, as recent scandals over allocation of telecommunication spectrum, land and mining rights, and over the economic and environmental depredations of the corporate ruling class. Pressure rises for short-term populist measures in the form of subsidies, handouts and loan waivers.


Even though these measures are taken in the name of the poor, the relatively rich grab most. For example, diesel subsidies meant for tractors and trucks end up going toward luxury cars of the rich; fertilizer subsidies mainly go to the wealthiest farmers; and a large part of the food subsidy is diverted by middlemen and non-target groups. The consequent budget deficits, now running up to 8 percent of GDP, often hurt the cause of pro-poor long-term investments in physical infrastructure and programs of education, vocational training and health care. India’s rickety physical and social infrastructure, hobbling its development, is a direct outcome of the democratic malaise of competitive populism.


In the United States, public anger over lost jobs and foreclosed homes is utilized by the rich to mobilize opinion for income tax cuts and against sensible energy prices or carbon taxes. The budget crisis negates or postpones pro-poor investments, like those in the battered physical infrastructure and the ramshackle US institutions of health care and education.


Policy gridlock


Another fallout of dysfunctional democracy in both countries is the refusal to compromise on the part of opposing political parties.


Collective action has always been difficult in India’s extremely heterogeneous and conflict-ridden society. With the decline of the national parties that used to have some semblance of encompassing interests, their dependence on shaky coalitions at the center, comes at the expense of long-term policy consolidation. The opposition parties block reforms that they themselves advocated while in power.


In the United States, political parties find gridlock because of narrow ideological and special interests preferable to compromise for the long run, legislative filibusters and other devices of checks and balances form a chokehold on major policy decisions. The Republican Party’s congressional leadership and presumptive presidential candidate are hobbled by demands of no compromise by the social conservative base, not to mention their super-rich backers. The Democrats are tied by union and special-interest connections.


Changing the system

It’s time both democracies pay some attention to devising new institutional mechanisms for insulating long-term decision-taking from the wheeling-dealing of everyday politics. Both need more independent regulatory and bipartisan policymaking bodies, with some power over the contours of long-run policy, with only periodic supervision or oversight by the clamorous legislatures. In both countries some attempts to increase public financing of elections and reduce the power of big money in funding political campaigns may alleviate the need of politicians to look constantly for funding sources and dance to the tune of special interests.

Attempts to reduce the extreme economic inequalities may increase trust in government and make it easier to persuade most people to make short-run sacrifices for the long-run benefits of all. Difficult though it is, doing something about inequality, corruption and political fragmentation, and installing some long-term commitment devices, may enormously help all political systems, democratic or otherwise. In particular restoring trust in governance and some sense of fairness in the system of wealth distribution will be necessary if the political regimes in China, India and the United States are to survive.


YaleGlobal


Pranab Bardhan is a professor of economics at the University of California, Berkeley.

No comments:

Post a Comment