The TPP is an agreement between 12
countries with very different economies but all of who are members of APEC
(Australia, Brunei, Canada, Chile, Japan, Malaysia, Mexico, New Zealand, Peru,
Singapore, the US and Vietnam). The TTIP is a bilateral negotiation. They have
much in common but also much that differentiates them.
Commitments to trade multilateralism
under the aegis of the WTO have, over the last decade, weakened in the face of
protectionist urges after the 2008 financial crisis and the rising pressures
for mega-regional Preferential Trading Arrangements (PTAs) and smaller regional
trading arrangements (RTA). Notwithstanding a broad consensus amongst
economists and trade policy officials that PTAs and RTAs are sub-optimal when
compared with multilateralism, they continue to flourish. Explanations for the
adoption of second-best strategies are driven more by political considerations
than economic ones. The Trans Pacific Partnership (TPP) and the Transatlantic Trade
and Investment Partnership (TTIP) conform to this pattern. They are
products of politics as much as economics. Either way, the success or failure
of either project will cast policy shadows over the evolution of the global
trade regime in the next decade with attendant implications for the states of
the Asia Pacific and Europe. There are lessons for Europe to learn from the
Asia Pacific experience.
Introduction
The Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP)
has been signed but not ratified and the Transatlantic Trade and Investment
Partnership (TTIP) negotiations are in train. The former faces challenges in
securing legislative ratification in the US and some other member states, buts
its progress faces widespread, and growing, resistance in key European
countries, with opposition coming from both within national bodies politic and
wider civil societies. The success of both projects hangs in the balance. This
short paper looks at the cases for and against both projects and analyses the
political dynamics at play. Putting its judgment upfront, the paper’s
conclusions are threefold: (1) Europe has much to learn from the TPP
experience; (2) assuming a Clinton victory in the forthcoming US presidential
election, the TPP has more chance of success than the TTIP at this time; and
(3) the TTIP’s chances are further diminished by a likely UK departure from the
EU.
TPP and TTIP compared
The TPP is an agreement between 12
countries with very different economies but all of who are members of APEC
(Australia, Brunei, Canada, Chile, Japan, Malaysia, Mexico, New Zealand, Peru,
Singapore, the US and Vietnam). The TTIP is a bilateral negotiation. They have
much in common but also much that differentiates them. Ostensibly their broad
aims are almost identical –and ambitious– although at different stages of
development: to further integrate the trans-Pacific and trans-Atlantic market
places.
The TTP negotiations concluded in
early October 2015 with the legal text being signed on 4 February 2016. To
‘enter into force’ all members must ratify the agreement. If this has not
happened after two years, then it can enter into force if six of the 12 members
representing 85% of the total GDP of the group ratify it. The US, with nearly
62%, and Japan, with over 17% of total GDP, effectively have a veto over
ratification. Anti-trade populism is currently a source of considerable concern
in the US and features strongly not only in Europe but also in the current US
presidential election. Donald Trump is opposed. Hillary Clinton is trimming for
political purposes but can be expected to come on board if elected.
The TTIP negotiations are entering a
very difficult phase with an unprecedented and articulate opposition skilled in
the use of modern social-media technologies and at a time of acute
multi-dimensional crisis in the European project. The TTIP, like the TPP, must
be seen as a logical extension to the wider elite-driven foreign economic
policy of both the US and the EU. It also reflects a frustration with the
failed multilateral trade negotiations (MTN) during the lost decade of the Doha
round. It also reflects a commitment of both Washington and Brussels policy
elites (to be distinguished from much activist civil society and populist
politics) to engage in ‘competitive trade liberalisation’ that attacks ‘behind
the border’ non-tariff barriers (NTBs) in the service and finance sectors –the
sectors that now dominate trans-Atlantic trade–.
The case for TPP and TTIP
There are basically five arguments
in favour of both agreements. First, the TPP is seen as a major step forward in
opening up trade in goods between the member countries. And it should be noted
that, in contrast to trans-Atlantic trade, trade in goods is still more
important in the Pacific than trade in services. The combined population of the
12 members of the TPP is just under 800 million and the total GDP is
approximately US$28.5 trillion. Advocates of the TPP point out that roughly 98%
of tariffs in the region will be eliminated and trade facilitation measures
will ensure that goods are moved between members as freely as possible (USTR). Supporters of the
TPP see potential income gains by 2025 of US$295 billion, of which US$78
billion would go to the US and US$119 billion to Japan (Hamilton, 2014, p. 83).
As with the TPP, the TTIP is argued
to possess the potential to deliver substantial economic benefits on both sides
of the Atlantic and, like the TPP, given its size it is not just another trade
deal. Indeed, it is the size of the interactions, both in absolute and
comparative terms that the TTIP boosters identify as an important incentive.
They stress US and European control of 75% of global financial markets, 50 % of
global GDP in terms of value and 41% in PPP terms, in excess of 40% of global
trade in services and 33% of global trade in goods, 57% of inward FDI and 75%
of outward FDI, half of which goes to each other. US investment in Europe was,
as late as 2011, still four times greater than in Asia (Hamilton, 2014, p.
82-3). Actual economic gains from the TTIP were initially calculated as high as
US$159 billion per year for the EU and US$127 billion for the US.
Secondly, the proponents of both the
TPP and the TTIP point to NTBs as the biggest remaining obstacle to trade. As
is well understood in the economic literature, the multiple rounds of GATT
multilateral trade negotiations throughout the second half of the 20th century
successfully whittled away the tariff as the main instrument of protection.
Champions of both agreements see the dismantling of ‘behind the borders’
measures as the final frontier.
The major NTB identified by both
projects is ‘regulatory incoherence’ –that is, bureaucratic and regulatory
obstacles to trade–. It is argued that some regulations exist simply to make it
more expensive for foreign firms to sell goods into home markets, thus
protecting home firms. The harmonisation of regulation, it is argued, would
undermine the protective practices of NTBs. At the very least, it is argued, it
offers a framework for a continuing trans-Pacific and trans-Atlantic dialogue
and greater acceptance of common standards (Chia, 2015) –what is often referred
to as ‘a living agreement’ that will continue after the formal Agreement comes
into being–. Moreover, regulatory harmonisation will create a fairer playing
field and make it easier for foreign firms to compete for public procurement
contracts by limiting the subsidies, discriminatory treatment and favouritism
afforded to state-owned enterprises.
Third, an Investor State Dispute
Settlement (ISDS) mechanism in both agreements is argued to encourage
trans-Pacific and trans-Atlantic investment and afford better protection for
investors. ISDS mechanisms are not new, having been incorporated into bilateral
agreements since the 1950s. The argument in their favour is that the updating
of these rules will encourage investments in countries with weaker legal
regimes at the same time as they control for abuse.
Fourth, both agreements aim to work
towards common labour and environmental standards, putting all members on an
equal footing when exporting goods and services.
Fifth, both bodies are seen as a
leading-edge 21st century agreements setting higher threshold standards for
future trade and investment agreements. Whatever their differences, the US and
the EU have higher threshold standards than big developing countries –notably
China, India, Mexico and other DCs trying to extract funds from a highly
competitive global investment market–. Agreed higher standards through The TPP
and the TTIP will give the US added leverage with the emerging trading
countries. Any future requests for accession to the TPP or the TTIP would have
to accept these thresholds. In
the words of Edward Alden ‘… these arrangements are the best
opportunity available for rich-world governments to gain a bit more control’.
The case against TPP and TTIP
Opponents of the TPP and the TTIP
have a variety of criticisms to make.
First, the negotiations and some of
the provisions of both Agreements are said to be anti-democratic. The lack of
transparency and the denial of democracy is a common cry (see, for instance,
Ville & Siles-Brugge, 2015). This has some substance in both cases but
perhaps more in Asia Pacific than across the Atlantic. During the TPP
negotiations, corporate lobbyists were consulted extensively but no meaningful
consultations took place with consumer groups, taxpayer organisations, union
organisations, healthcare professionals or environmentalists. Even elected
representatives, such as US members of Congress, were given only restricted
access to the negotiating documents that they were not allowed to further
discuss. Detractors, therefore, see the TPP as an agreement negotiated in the
interests of major corporations, not of the populations of the member countries
(Reich, 2015). Similar views are to be found in the oppositions of other TPP
countries.
The TTIP evokes similar objections.
The actors are the same: government negotiators, consumer groups, labour
organisations, environmentalist and other interested CSOs. But opposition from
such groups has been stronger and more extensive and fiercely articulated in
Europe than in the Pacific. This can be explained by the differing levels of
political development in the two regions and especially the fact that labour,
environmental and consumer standards are lower in Asia than in Europe. The TPP
can be expected to enhance standards in many of the US’s Asian partners
(Australia and New Zealand excepted); thus, resistance is weaker than in
Europe, where the view is that TTIP will challenge standards already higher
there than in the US.
Moreover, and also in contrast to
the Asia Pacific, negotiations across the Atlantic are bi-lateral and the
European Commission, representing 28 European states needs to be accountable to
a wide range of decision groups. Democratic control is present and, in the last
instance, details of the Agreement will still need to be approved by the
European Parliament. Civil society, value-based driven opposition to trade
negotiations is not new, as the history of the WTO attests. But public debate
about the TTIP on both sides of the Atlantic is robust. The opposition to the
TTIP is certainly more informed, more articulate and perhaps less
ideologically-driven than opposition to the birth of the WTO or the TPP. In
addition, the EC has tried hard –although not without criticism– to utilise
good governance principles of openness and participation in the TTIP
decision-making process.
Secondly, the benefits of both
agreements are argued to be grossly overstated and the drawbacks equally
understated. For example, opponents of the TPP in developed countries –and the
US in particular– see previous trade agreements, such as NAFTA and the recent
Korean-US FTA, as contributing to the hollowing out of the industrial and
manufacturing sectors and the shipping of jobs offshore. The TPP, they argue,
will mean more of the same (Harford, 2016; Wallach, 2016).
In the case of the TTIP, assertions
that it will be a major source of economic growth have lost traction. As the
negotiations have progressed, the putative macroeconomic effects, on GDP growth,
have been scaled back (Capaldo, 2104). Moreover, these gains (between 0.2% and
0.4% of GDP for the US by 2027 and 0.3%-0.5% for the EU) would also be
accompanied by a net loss to most workers and an increase in inequality
(Rosnick, 2015). But these are not simply European concerns. As they do with
the TPP, opponents of the TTIP in the US worry about negative macroeconomic
effects exacerbating job losses and declining manufacturing industries
(especially in the automobile industry in the face of European competition).
Third, critics of both agreements
resist arguments about the benefits of regulatory reform. Specifically,
European opponents of the TTIP resist the notion of ‘regulatory incoherence’.
Rather, they assume that government regulation addresses challenges in areas of
human development, notably health, agriculture and the environment. Opponents
see a fundamental incompatibility between US and European philosophies on
regulation. Europe adopts a precautionary principle in contrast to the US cost-benefit
analysis-driven approach to regulation. As Ackerman (2016, p. 4-5)
demonstrates, the savings from just two key European regulatory policies alone
–(a) the Registration, Evaluation, Authorisation and Restriction of Chemicals
(REACH) and (b) renewable energy standards– could be up to €110 billion a year,
a figure that equates to the best guestimate of Europe’s trade gains from the
TTIP. The TTIP, opponents argue, would put at risk those benefits –especially
in the domains of health, environmental sustainability, labour and social
standards– that European regulation is deemed to have enhanced in the early
21st century.
Fourth, ISDS mechanisms give foreign
corporations the right to by-pass domestic courts in favour of an international
tribunal to seek compensation for policies that interfere with their ability to
make a profit. While there are some restrictions on corporations’ rights to
sue, those who are against this chapter of the agreements argue that it
severely limits the sovereignty of democratically elected governments,
particularly in policy areas such as the environment and public health issues
and the regulation of sectors such as real estate and finance (Warren, 2015).
As noted earlier, these are new to neither the TPP nor the TTIP. They have been
instruments of US bilateral trade deals in the past, but by limiting the public
policy space afforded governments the pendulum is said to have swung too far
towards investor protection and away from the rights of consumers and workers.
The EC insists that it resists the
argument that the TTIP is a race to the bottom. Yet opponents, including even members of the TTIP Advisory
Group, argue this may still not ward off the lowering of standards
in areas where Europe and the US see things differently –climate and energy
policy, food safety, chemicals, data protection, public procurement and labour
standards– and where the measures to support downwards harmonisation would need
to be made to introduced to secure agreement.
Fifth, and in similar vein, those
against the Intellectual Property Rights (IPR) chapters of the Agreements also
see an excessive protection of investor rights. For example, in the TPP
Agreement the rights of IP holders are referred to as ‘mandatory’ while those
of users are generally noted as ‘optional’. Similarly, the extension of
copyright provisions and, often disproportionate, penalties for their
infringement are also resisted. The most frequently cited problem is the
increase in the cost of pharmaceuticals that will result from the IPR
provisions (Geist, 2016). Opponents argue they lock in place the existing
economic and technological hierarchy among members. Those TTP countries that
produce high-tech products and hold large numbers of patents –essentially the
US and Japan– will be able to protect their high-tech industries while
resource-extraction countries and low-cost manufacturers will find it difficult
to move up the technological ladder.
Sixth, both agreements, like other
US bilateral FTAs, are seen in Asia and Europe as negatively asymmetrical. From
a specifically European perspective some even argue they reflect a clash of
models of capitalist organisation where the issues at stake are not simply
trade concessions. Rather, they see the TTIP redefining the very relationship
between states, the market and the large global corporate actors who make, or
at least shape, markets. Regulation for the opponents of the TTIP is not simply
an economic matter; it is a political choice about how to govern global
capitalism. For the former distinguished Eurocrat Pierre Defraigne, the TTIP is
‘… une offensive frontale contre le modèle européene’ (2016, p. 11-13 passim.).
Mega-regionalism and the geo-politics of TPP and TTIP
The previous section has presented in
brief the ‘for’ and ‘against’ case for TPP and TTIP. Clearly there is a
considerable overlap in both sets of arguments. More generally, both projects
reflect the major shift away from multilateralism towards (mega) regionalism.
The regionalisation (and politicisation) of trade policy is not new. Regional
(and bilateral) FTAs and PTAs have been around for a long time and they are
often as much politico-strategically driven as economically driven. Indeed,
after 9/11 FTAs became integral to the ‘securitisation’ of US foreign economic
policy (see Higgott, 2004). But there are differences between the TPP and the
TTIP on the one hand and standard FTAs on the other.
First and most obviously, the TPP
and the TTIP, while they are meant to be trade liberalising negotiations,
extend far beyond in terms of both their ambition and their size. The TPP and
the TTIP together account for two thirds of global output.
Secondly, beyond standard trade
negotiations, traditionally focussed on tariff reductions, they aspire to bring
about a major normative change in the global trade order in the areas of
standard setting, the harmonisation of regulation and dispute settlement
–pushing out beyond the agenda of the increasingly marginalised WTO–.
There are also specific differences
between the TPP and the: (a) one argument in favour of the TPP, although not
presented as part of the public argument in Asia, is that it will enhance the
growth of democracy in a way that is, in theory at least, less necessary in the
TTIP; and (b) the TPP is expected to enhance labour and environmental standards
in Asia, while this argument carries less weight in Europe where the fear is
rather that the TTIP will attack such standards.
Thirdly, the negotiations are different
to the extent that the TPP is both a multilateral negotiation between the 12
partners and a series of cross-partner bilateral discussions; especially
between the US and those members of the TPP that do not have a bilateral FTA
with it. By contrast, the TTIP is effectively a bilateral negotiation between
Washington and Brussels.
Fourthly, for the US, the two
projects are seen as exercises to revitalise its wider trans-oceanic
relationships and contain the growing power of ‘rival’ poles of influence, notably
China in Asia and a recrudescent Russia in Europe. As the US Ambassador to the
EU, Anthony Gardner, unambiguously
puts it: ‘the winning argument for TTIP is the geo-political
argument… It’s about re-booting the trans-Atlantic partnership’. Such an
approach is not without dangers. The emotional intensity of the debate over the
TTIP in Europe (Germany and France in particular) appears to be exacerbating
anti-Americanism (see Kundnani, 2016). The TTIP, rather than becoming
Hamilton’s (2015) ‘second anchor’ for the trans-Atlantic relationship could in
fact generate as much friction as harmony if the negotiations deadlock.
Without elaboration here, the
politico-security context in Europe is different to that in Asia. If the TTIP
is to carry geo-strategic significance as both concept and practice then it
needs to be driven by a wider set of (preferably universalised) values other
than geographically defined economic interest, especially in an era of growing
national populism. Placing geo-strategic value on regional trade arrangements
is always politically risky. The TTIP and the TPP are both reflections of the
politicisation of preferential trade activity similar to that of many PTAs over
the last 20 years. But while many of those were small, bilateral and
asymmetrical, there are much bigger stakes in play with the TPP and the TTIP.
The former has been central to the Obama strategy of Asian re-balancing in the
face of the rise of China (see Tellis, 2014). The TTIP is seen as a way to
address European fears that the pivot to Asia might represent a lessening US
commitment to Europe. Should either fail then there will clearly be negative
consequences for the wider credibility of US foreign policy.
Finally, both exercises will not
remain untouched by the British decision to exit the EU. The implications are
greater for the TTIP than the TPP, but the latter is not immune. Clearly it is
too early to say anything definitive but several self-evident implications can
be noted. It certainly demands a larger role from Asia in containing any
knock-on effects for the global economy, especially the degree to which Brexit may
hit global growth outlooks and carry negative externalities for the
continued openness of the global trade regime.
The implications for the TTIP are
not clear. On the one hand, there is currently no Brussels plan for EU trade
policy without UK membership. Certainly, the departure of the UK shrinks the EU
market and weakens EU leverage with the US, which has always seen the UK as the
strong liberal counterweight to the more economically statist EU members in the
negotiations, such as France and Italy. Simply put, Brexit will give the
protectionist political voices in the EU more influence. On the other hand,
trade is the competence solely of the EU, not individual member states, and the
desire for talks with the US remains strong in most European capitals. The
concerns of opponents to the TTIP outlined in this paper exist irrespective of
Brexit and some argue that the UK’s exclusion from the negotiations could
even free up some areas of EU trade policy, for example in trade
defence instruments.
But the UK accounts for 25% of all
US exports to the EU. It is possible that outside the EU, the UK may achieve
terms more favourable than it would have within it. Conversely, the EU could
achieve less favourable terms. More importantly, and if as looks likely, the US
and UK enter into a bilateral trade negotiation, then any trade deal between
the US and the EU is unlikely to be finalised until the US has settled terms
with the UK. By voting to leave the EU, the UK has in fact leapfrogged the
queue and put itself in a pivotal position in EU/US trade negotiations.
Conclusions
As a consequence of their ambition,
both the TPP and the TTIP are highly contentious. Most leaders who signed the
TPP are strong advocates of the Agreement, as are major corporations who will
gain from its implementation. But large numbers of people have taken to the
streets in member countries to demonstrate against the Agreement. And a wide
range of civil society groups –from union and environmental organisations to
health professionals, to Presidential candidates– do not support the TPP. While
ratification of the TPP may well occur in both the two major partners –the US
and Japan–, in neither country is it assured (Mulgan, 2016). The completion of
the TTIP looks even more difficult. Only begun in June 2013, negotiations are
running several years behind the TPP and progress in the negotiations is
proving protracted and contested. If negotiations are not secured prior to
President Obama’s departure, then a pre-2021 completion is unlikely.
It is not just an articulate
anti-TTIP lobby that has successfully mobilised against it, senior national
politicians –in France and Germany especially– also have reservations and both
countries have general elections in 2017. Such has been the success of the
opposition to the TTIP, especially to the ISDS provisions, that both US and EU
government officials are highly sensitised to the need to engage more with
non-official stakeholders than has been the case in many a trade negotiation in
the past. In response to the opposition, the EU has come up with a set of
reforms likely to prove unacceptable to the US. Similarly, in the face of
opposition to the US proposal for liberalisation of trade in services, the EU
has proposed over 200 exclusions, many of which would also prove unacceptable
to the US. There is also no sign that agreement would be reached any time soon
on contentious issues in agriculture, especially genetically-modified crops,
antibiotics, hormones in beef and geographical indications.
Thus are the politics and economics
of TTIP inextricably intertwined and largely unresolved and there are several
specific take-home messages for Europe to be had from the Asia Pacific
experience to-date. Notably, many of the issues are less contentious in the
Pacific than in Europe. This is explained by a number of factors including: (a)
the different levels of both economic and political development in the two regions;
(b) that the opposition is less developed (and in some instances less free to
oppose) in the Pacific than in Europe; and (c) that the negotiations also have
a difference of emphasis. In particular, the issue of regulatory harmonisation
has been less of a political hot potato in the TPP than in the TTIP. This in
part reflects the fact that services are a more important dimension of the
trans-Atlantic economy than they are currently in Asia-Pacific, where trade in
goods still, for now, predominate. Opponents of the TTIP see regulatory
harmonisation as more of a fundamental challenge than was the case in Asia
Pacific. The departure of the UK from the EU, a stronger supporter of
regulatory harmonisation, and indeed the TTIP in general will only make trans-Atlantic
agreement in this area even more difficult.
Further, not only has the ostensibly
less controversial CETA negotiation been slowed down, but any idea of ‘fast
tracking’ the agreement has gone, and grass-roots opposition to the TTIP is
also stronger than is often assumed, as protectionist rhetoric appears to grow
stronger on both sides of the Atlantic. Even in Germany, where it is set to be
an issue in the forthcoming Federal election, support
for it is at only 17%. At this stage the most likely outcome is that
the TTIP’s progress grinds to a halt.
At the macro level, the key
comparative and contextual lesson to be had from an observation of the TPP and
TTIP projects is that they represent a fundamental change in the attitudes of
economic and corporate elites towards the management of the global trade system
in the 21st century and nowhere more so than in the US and the other major
economic powers. Trade negotiations since the turn of the century, and
especially since the financial crises of 2008, now increasingly privilege
(mega) regional over WTO-style multilateral activity. This activity is driven
as much by geo-political consideration as any desire for trade liberalisation
with all the attendant negative implications for the future of the WTO in
particular but multilateralism in general. The yet to be resolved question is
whether these trends in thinking and practice about the global economy can
resist the growing populist opposition to them.
About the author:
*Richard Higgott, Emeritus Professor of International Political Economy, University of Warwick, Distinguished Professor of Diplomacy, Vesalius College, and Research Professor, Institute of European Studies at the Vrije Universiteit Brussel
*Richard Higgott, Emeritus Professor of International Political Economy, University of Warwick, Distinguished Professor of Diplomacy, Vesalius College, and Research Professor, Institute of European Studies at the Vrije Universiteit Brussel
Source:
This article was published by Elcano Royal Institute
This article was published by Elcano Royal Institute
References:
Ackerman, Frank (2016), ‘Europe’s Regulations at Risk: The Environmental Costs of TTIP’, Global Economic Governance Initiative, The Frederick S. Pardee School of Global Studies, Boston University.
Ackerman, Frank (2016), ‘Europe’s Regulations at Risk: The Environmental Costs of TTIP’, Global Economic Governance Initiative, The Frederick S. Pardee School of Global Studies, Boston University.
Capoldo, Jeronin, (2014), ‘The Trans-Atlantic Trade and
Investment Partnership: European Disintegration, Unemployment and Instability’,
Global Development and Environment Institute, Working Paper nr 14-03, Tufts
University.
Chia Yan Min (2015), ‘10
Benefits the Trans-Pacific Partnership Will Bring Singapore’, The
Straits Times, 16/XI/2015.
Defraigne, Pierre (2016), ‘L’Europe
entre partnenariat atlantique et allegiance: le veritable enjeu du TTIP’,
Madariaga College of Europe Centre, Brussels.
Geist, Michael (2016), ‘The
Trouble with the TPP’.
Harford, Tim (2016), ‘Trump,
Trade and “The China Shock”’, Financial Times, 24/III/2016.
Higgott, Richard (2004), ‘US Foreign
Economic Policy and the Securitisation of Globalisation’, International
Politics, nr 41, Summer, p. 147-175.
Kundnani, Hans (2106), ‘TTIP
must die to the West can live’, Foreign Policy Online.
Mulgan, Aurelia George (2016), ‘Japan:
Shinto Abe’s upcoming election test: will Japan’s farmers revolt against the
LDP in the July Upper House election?’, The Diplomat,
24/III/2016.
Reich, Robert (2015), ‘Why the
Trans-Pacific Partnership Agreement is a Pending Disaster’,
5/I/2015.
Tellis, Ashley (2014) Balancing
Without Containment: An American Strategy for Managing China, Carnegie Endowment,
Washington.
Ville, F.D., & G. Siles-Brugge
(2015), TTIP: The Truth about the Transatlantic Trade and Investment
Partnership, Polity.
Wallach, Lori (2016) ‘The
Choice is Not Between TPP or No Trade’, Huffpost Politics,
24/III//2016.
Warren, Senator Elizabeth, (2015) ‘Senator Warren on
the Trans-Pacific Partnership Agreement’, 26/II/2015.
Elcano
Royal Institute
The Elcano Royal Institute
(Real Instituto Elcano) is a private entity, independent of both the Public
Administration and the companies that provide most of its funding. It was
established, under the honorary presidency of HRH the Prince of Asturias, on 2 December
2001 as a forum for analysis and debate on international affairs and
particularly on Spain’s international relations. Its output aims to be of use
to Spain’s decision-makers, both public and private, active on the
international scene. Its work should similarly promote the knowledge of Spain
in the strategic scenarios in which the country’s interests are at stake.
Did you know that you can make cash by locking special sections of your blog or website?
ReplyDeleteSimply open an account on AdWorkMedia and use their content locking widget.