The claim’s logical conclusion is that abolishing the policy will eliminate
China’s sex ratio imbalance.
But some basic comparisons show us how the conventional wisdom is faulty.
The claim that the skewed
sex ratio has occurred due to the birth planning policy usually rests on two
premises: that it alone caused fertility decline and that this fertility
decline led to a skewed sex ratio at birth. But, in fact, China’s fertility
decline began in the early 1970s, years before the one-child policy. And, China’s
neighbours had similar fertility declines in the 1970, even without such
draconian policies.
Fertility declines also do
not inevitably lead to a skewed sex ratio. Japan’s fertility rate
has been among the world’s lowest for nearly two decades, but its sex ratio at birth has remained
in the natural range. While China’s skewed sex ratio of the past
three decades does coincide with the start of the birth planning policy, this
coincidence is somewhat misleading. A longer historical view reveals that
China’s sex ratio was terribly skewed over much of the last two centuries.
The one-child policy
itself is a bit of a misnomer: three distinct policy variations are in place
across China. Rural, majority-Han areas practice a ‘1.5-child’ policy, in which
families whose first child is a girl are allowed a second in hopes of having a
boy. Urban areas have a strict one-child limit, while poor ethnic-minority
areas have a two-child limit.
Sex ratio skewing is higher in rural 1.5-child policy areas
(about 119:100 at birth) than in urban one-child areas (about 115:100), and is
lowest in two-child policy areas (about 112:100). These numbers indicate that
switching to a universal two-child policy would reduce but not eliminate the
problem: China’s sex ratio at birth would still be higher than almost anywhere
else in the world. So there is some truth to the conventional wisdom, but the
birth planning policy is not the only important driver of sex ratio skewing.
The problem with the
conventional wisdom is that it treats son preference as a cultural given: it
says Chinese people just prefer sons. But son preference is not a constant.
Incentives for Chinese families to have sons have changed considerably over
time, rising and falling in tandem with a skewed sex ratio at birth. So efforts
to normalise China’s sex ratio at birth ought to attack existing incentives for
families to have sons.
Son preference incentives
appear in four realms: labour, property
ownership and inheritance, ritual life, and old-age security.
Societies with strong incentives in these areas tend to have a skewed sex
ratio. Indeed, differences in the sex ratio at birth parallel differences in
levels of son preference incentives through time, across regions of China and
across countries. Old-age security seems to be the most important driver of son
preference, while ritual-related incentives matter less.
China’s sex ratio at birth
was skewed before 1960, normal during 1960–85 and skewed again after 1985. In
both periods of high skewing, sons were highly necessary on all four measures:
for farm labour, property inheritance, ancestor worship and old-age care. In
contrast, during the communist era (approximately 1958–83), production was
socialised, property was collectivised, ancestor worship was suppressed and
pensions for the elderly were provided by the commune. Families didn’t require
sons, and so they had little incentive to practice female infanticide or
abandonment.
Since the mid-1980s, son
preference incentives have differed starkly between urban and rural areas of
China. In urban areas, educated women make important economic contributions to
their birth families and are thus able to provide old-age care for their
parents. Ancestor worship is also less relevant to urban life compared to rural
areas, while urban women also share equally in property and inheritance.
Altogether, these factors mean that urban families have less incentive than
rural ones to prefer sons.
The sex ratio at birth has
also changed along with son preference incentives in Japan and
South Korea. Japan scores low on our measures of son preference throughout the
20th century. Women contribute meaningfully to family income and inherit
property equally, and Japan has excellent old-age pensions. While sons are
strongly preferred for family rituals, Japan’s sex ratio at birth is not
skewed. As a second example, South Korea saw a sharp increase in sex ratio
skewing in the mid-1980s, followed by a decrease after 1995.
This normalisation coincided with changes in South Korean family law specifying
that women did not have to marry into their husbands’ families, had equal
rights and responsibilities in ancestor worship and equal inheritance rights.
Normalising China’s skewed
sex ratio will require a concerted effort to reduce son preference, targeting
policies and institutions that create these incentives. Simply haranguing
Chinese citizens to change their ‘backward’ ways of thinking and culture will
not suffice.
Elizabeth Remick is an
associate professor of political science at Tufts University. Charis Loh is an
independent scholar.
This article is based on a
paper by the authors published in the China Quarterly.
No comments:
Post a Comment