To the extent
that Abenomics depends on Bank of Japan (BOJ) Governor Haruhiko Kuroda’s
quantitative and qualitative easing program, the experiment is insulated from
the vagaries of public opinion. However, from the beginning, the BOJ’s radical
measures to defeat deflation were only a first step towards a broader
revitalisation and transformation of the Japanese economy that would strengthen
Japan’s global competitiveness and raise its long-term growth potential.
Restoring inflation would create the right economic and political environment
to implement extensive reforms to the labour market (including increasing the
role of women in the workforce) and the inefficient agricultural and service
sectors, foster a new system of corporate governance to generate greater
returns for investors, and reshape how the public and private sectors invest in
next-generation technologies.
To realise
these policy changes, which have in many cases been pursued by Japanese prime
ministers for decades, Abe would have to overcome resistance from entrenched
interests in the bureaucracy, the ruling Liberal Democratic Party (LDP) and in
the economy more broadly, wielding strong public support — and the vote of
confidence in Abenomics from foreign investors in the form of buoyant equity
markets — as a weapon against defenders of the status quo.
Despite his
rhetoric, Abe has proven to be a reluctant reformer, unable to translate his political
capital into concrete policy outcomes. His 2013 and 2014 growth strategies, the
centrepieces of the so-called ‘third arrow’ of Abenomics, have disappointed,
signifying more a return to old-style industrial policy than a dramatic break
with past practice. When it comes to difficult structural reforms like labour
market reform, the growth strategies have offered only modest changes and do
little to introduce more flexibility or reverse the growth of low-paid
part-time and other temporary employment.
More
significantly, in setting lengthy implementation timelines, the Abe government
has allowed bureaucrats, LDP backbenchers and lobbyists to fill in the details
of the strategy’s skeletal proposals, further watering down the government’s
reform agenda. With most of the 2014 growth strategy’s legislative items
delayed until the 2015 regular session of the Diet, Abe continues to show no
great urgency in his pursuit of structural reform.
Why have Abe’s
achievements thus far lagged behind his promises?
The reasons
are numerous. First, structural reform is difficult. Were it easy, one of Abe’s
reform-minded predecessors would surely have found a way to achieve it. But in
practice, structural reform means uprooting economic institutions that have
endured since the 1930s, when they were introduced by Japan’s militarist
government and then were retained by the post-war US occupation.
As the leader
of a messy, pluralistic democracy populated by interest groups that have
profited from existing institutions, Abe cannot simply change the Japanese
economy by decree. Of course, Abe’s pursuit of structural reform is further
complicated by the fact that his LDP has profited from the status quo more than
most. The LDP is at best ambivalent about structural reform and, despite Abe’s
personal popularity and the broader power shift to the prime minister’s office,
the party is still capable of undermining the government’s agenda, as happened
when Abe’s regulatory reform council floated a proposal to abolish JA-Zenchu,
the national council of agricultural cooperatives. The reform council’s trial
balloon met with fierce resistance from LDP backbenchers who forced the
government to back away from outright abolition and allow JA-Zenchu to
participate in the reform process.
Finally, Abe
may himself be ambivalent about reform or, at the very least, be reluctant to
engage in open conflict with members of his own party about structural reform.
It is significant that one of Abe’s first decisions when he became prime
minister for the first time in 2006 was to readmit LDP members who had been
expelled from the party in 2005 for opposing the postal system reforms of the
then prime minister, Junichiro Koizumi. Abe appears to prefer stability to
reform, which may make for durable government but which makes economic
transformation less likely.
If Abe’s
popularity has in fact peaked, it is even less likely that he will be able to
deliver the long-term economic revitalisation he has promised. Instead, as his
political capital declines—and as his government prepares for local elections
in April 2015 and legislative elections sometime in 2016—he may be tempted to
pursue politically expedient policies rather than difficult but necessary
reforms. This logic may guide the prime minister’s decision to devote the
forthcoming extraordinary session of the Diet to revitalising uncompetitive
rural regions, which could potentially bear fruit in next year’s nationwide
local elections.
But if Abe
shrinks from the challenge of structural reform, it raises an uncomfortable
question about whether Japan’s economy can be reformed at all. If a prime
minister with historically high levels of public support, command of both
houses of the Diet and the approval of foreign investors and international
organisations cannot prosecute anything more than incremental changes to
long-standing economic institutions, can anyone?
Tobias Harris
is an analyst at Teneo Intelligence, the political risk arm of strategic
consultancy Teneo.
A longer
version of this article appeared in the most recent edition of the East Asia Forum
Quarterly, ‘A
Japan that can say ‘yes’‘.
No comments:
Post a Comment