Rice and rubber subsidies will blight the budget, without
helping rural areas.
Thailand's year-old policy of
subsidizing producers of its two major export crops, rice and rubber, has
obvious negative implications for government finances. But the development
challenge underlying this misbegotten intervention remains salient for many
middle-income countries: How to keep rural incomes from falling ever further
behind those in urban areas?
Prime Minister Yingluck Shinawatra's
decision last year to buy up rice at a 40% premium over the global price was
motivated by a desire to help Thailand's rice farmers. These farmers were
demanding better redistribution of the nation's wealth—and, not coincidentally,
have been strong supporters of her Pheu Thai party.
The policy has already cost the
government about 260 billion baht ($8.4 billion) and another 400 billion baht
has been approved for the next 12 months. Similarly, following demonstrations
against falling rubber prices, the government pledged 15 billion baht for
rubber buying.
The costs of these policies are
clear. Rice prices this year enjoyed a brief uptick in the wake of the U.S.
drought but have generally remained weak. Meanwhile, the Thai government has
been accumulating stocks that can only be sold at a loss. Thais are producing
more rice thanks to the government support, but the price floor provides
incentive to growers to put quantity ahead of quality.
This comes at a time when other
countries are stepping up rice exports. Burma, once the world's major rice
exporter, is starting reforms that should soon enable it to take advantage of
its plentiful land and low labor costs to boost production and exports, much as
Vietnam did a decade ago.
Rubber could be a similar story.
Thai rubber smallholders enjoyed years of good prices which rose from 40 U.S.
cents per pound in 2002 to a peak of $2.65 in April 2011. Since then prices
have fallen to $1.26 despite government intervention.
This may not be merely a short-term
drop in a traditionally volatile commodity. The longer-term rubber cycle
appears to have turned, thanks to slackening global demand and the prospect of
large new acreage in Vietnam, Cambodia, Laos and Indonesia coming into
production. Rubber tapping is a labor-intensive business, so there is every
prospect of the Thai government becoming committed to almost permanent
subsidies if its rubber growers are to enjoy the standard of living which they
expect as Thais.
All this means that Thailand is
offering ever-larger subsidies it can ill afford. Barring unlikely sustained
surges in global prices for rice and rubber, Ms. Yingluck looks to have saddled
Thailand with subsidies that could prove even more difficult to remove than the
fuel subsidies that blight the budgets of a long list of Asian countries.
Also, scare stories about global
food shortages don't provide any justification. Prices do spike, but the
long-term price trend of most agricultural commodities remains negative. So the
cost of subsidizing a particular price level is likely to rise.
One can sympathize with governments
in semi-industrialized economies keen to avoid rural areas falling so far
behind the metropolis as to foment urban-rural tensions. Thailand is especially
prone to this problem after years of hostility that has occasionally broken
into violence. Nor is it alone. China's urban-rural income gap is far worse
than Thailand's, and only political repression keeps a lid on localized
discontent. Importing cheap plantation labor as Malaysia does delays the
problem but is no solution.
But that doesn't mean subsidies are
the right way forward. Rather, policy makers need to encourage rural incomes to
rise naturally through productivity gains. Efforts should be made to raise farm
productivity through mechanization, land consolidation and new technology.
In Thailand, as in other
middle-income countries, money would be better spent on promoting land and
labor productivity—both still low in rural Thailand. It's also time for Bangkok
to accept that so much land can no longer be economically farmed. Considering
rural populations are aging rapidly, Thailand needs price signals which will
encourage productivity not volume production. Subsidies distort these.
Meanwhile, subsidizing major rural
exports disadvantages other industries, and the farmers who grow unsubsidized
crops. If you are going to subsidize, direct it to investment in yields and
mechanization.
Then again, subsidies are easier
promised than paid for. The idea of some kind of farm subsidies remains
alluring because even the developed economies—despite their preaching of
free-trade deals—indulge in them. They're a fiscal drag for Europe and the
U.S., but these subsidies are minimal compared to the economy because farmers
comprise 3% to 5% of the workforce. In middle-income countries, when they're
20% to 30% of the workforce, there is a real risk of being stuck with a giant
bill.
Thailand is not alone in the
middle-income country problem of rural-urban income divides.
Regrettably, these
countries have nothing to learn from advanced countries—least of all those in
Asia like Japan and Korea—which routinely subsidize farm production. Ms.
Yingluck is misguided, but her mistake should focus attention on a very real
dilemma, one that is particularly pressing for those facing still large rural
electorates.
By Phillip Bowring Hong Kong-based
journalist. The Wall Street Journal
No comments:
Post a Comment